Monday, August 11, 2014

Spatial Accounting

Just published a post on Stat Chat dealing with how cities evaluate the costs and income associated with different neighborhood configurations.  As part of it, I mapped the value per acre in the City of Charlottesville and Albemarle County.



At almost the same time, Strong Towns posted an article arguing for many of the same things.

Thursday, June 19, 2014

A response to Wendell Cox

... who is at it again trying to stick his finger in the planners' eyes and prove that we need more highways and suburbs.  Jim Bacon summarizes his argument here.  I am essentially reposting the comment that I made there.

Cox argues that denser metro areas also have more traffic.  He argues that part of the reason is their unwillingness to build new highways and that less traffic can be an economic advantage for an area.


By Cox's reasoning, low-density Richmond should have a huge economic advantage since it has the least congestion of any major metro area.  Hampton Roads (which is actually even less dense than Richmond) doesn't fare quite as well but is still on the low end for traffic.

There are a couple of small problems even with this graph.  Bacon points out one - Cox fails to take into account that larger metro areas simply have more traffic regardless of their density - and that they also tend to get denser as more people try to stay connected to the core of the area.  Another is that he looks only at the delay during peak periods, which tells us how bad rush hour can be but isn't always a good metric for traffic in general.

But these are both minor points.  The real problem with Cox's analysis is that he makes a point that is correct and obvious, then draws or infers conclusions that are completely incorrect.  More density does, of course, mean more congestion.  If there are more people in a given area, there will be more of them going places and doing things.  And just building new transit or making areas walkable does not mean that there will be less visible traffic on the roads.  Because roads are free and convenient, people tend to max them out before shifting to other modes.  But more visible traffic is not a sign that density is dysfunctional, nor is it always a bad thing for cities, for several reasons.

First, he measures traffic congestion rather than access. The two are very, very different. Most people perceive the inconvenience of traffic in terms of how fast they can drive on a road, which is ridiculous. They ought to evaluate it in terms of their increased or decreased access to possible destinations. So yes, ten minutes of driving in Manhattan might barely get you a mile. But that mile driving radius gets you access to a million people, several million jobs, and tens of thousands of retail stores and restaurants.  Contrast that with suburban Richmond. Ten minutes of driving in Chesterfield County might get you geographically farther in any one direction (including time on side streets to get to destinations), but that only gives you access to less than a hundred thousand people, and not nearly the concentration of jobs or amenities. Cities create value by being markets and markets that can provide access to more people result in more value creation.  Part of that access also involves being able to use different modes based on the different circumstances of the trip. This mapping application, which is fantastic, gives a better idea of how much access cities are creating for their people and how traffic affects that: http://www.flaviogortana.com/isoscope/.

Here's a ten minute drive in Manhattan, covering an area inhabited by nearly a million people, with millions more jobs:




vs. Chesterfield County, where a ten minute drive gets you access to less than a hundred thousand people and jobs:


The same argument crops up between fire departments and planning departments.  Fire departments, worried about their response times, often push for large roads and unsafe pedestrian infrastructure that pushes people further out.  Even though they can't travel as quickly in denser cities, the concentration of people means more fire stations.  In central Boston, response times are a fourth of what they are in the outer suburbs.  Even here in Charlottesville, city stations can respond in less than half the time that county stations can, their complaints about narrow streets and tight corners notwithstanding.

Second, Cox fails to mention that, while traffic may correlate somewhat with density, it correlates even better with economic growth or decline. And that sort of invalidates his argument about a lack of traffic being a major draw. It is a draw – in the same sense that an empty room at a party is attractive if one room is overcrowded. But the whole reason you are at the party is to talk to people, so there is a reason the most crowded room tends to get more crowded over time until a group can form that’s large enough to spin off another conversation. The areas with the most traffic also tend to be the areas with the highest median incomes. Traffic is a sign that people have things to do and places to go.  When the economy tanks and unemployment rises, traffic tends to get lighter.

For years, planners and economists assumed a pretty tight relationship between vehicle miles traveled and GDP growth, and they were largely justified.  In the last five years, however, the situation has started to change.


Third, from a fiscal (and to a certain extent an environmental) perspective, more traffic, if it can be controlled by traffic management systems, means more efficient use of the roads. This is generally true at the metro area level that Cox is analyzing since most roads are far below capacity most of the time (it’s not necessarily true for a particular road after it reaches the congestion point). Areas that have very low traffic congestion are probably paying far too much for their roads given their (probably poor) economic power.

I will use this as yet another excuse to post my comparison of the amount of pavement per vehicle in Charlottesville vs the pavement per vehicle in suburban Albemarle County:


Thursday, June 5, 2014

How to Eliminate Gerrymandering

Massachussetts software engineer Brian Olson wrote an algorithm to allocate census blocks into optimally compact equal-population districts.

Chris Ingram writes on the Washington Post's political blog:

Yesterday, I asked readers how they felt about setting up independent commissions to handle redistricting in each state. Commenter Mitch Beales wrote: "It seems to me that an 'independent panel' is about as likely as politicians redistricting themselves out of office. This is the twenty-first century. How hard can it be to create an algorithm to draw legislative districts after each census?" Reader "BobMunck" agreed: "Why do people need to be involved in mapping the districts?"

Here's Virginia in 2010 according to Olson's algorithm.  Congress:


House of Delegates:





State Senate:





Jim Bacon had a post recently on Virginia's seeming stagnation when it comes to implementing new ideas in government.  How about being the first state to do this?

I am also a big fan of California's Proposition 14, which consolidates all primaries into a single election.  The two candidates receiving the highest number of votes then advance to the general election - essentially a runoff system similar to that used in many other countries.  It removes the incentives in the primary stage to cater to the most extreme parts of the base and allows less conventional combinations of political views that might have cross-party appeal to make a case to the whole public.

Either of these innovations might help us do something about the incredibly non-competitive (and therefore not particularly democratic) Virginia state legislature.

Thursday, May 1, 2014

Walmarts Over Downtowns II: Southwest VA

A lot of people have been interested in the Walmart visuals from a while back.  I had one request to do a few more for towns in southwest Virginia - and indeed I did neglect to include any from that area.  Here are five more.

Bristol (Walmart, Sam's Club, and Lowe's):


Christiansburg:


Galax:


Lebanon:


Wytheville:


Tuesday, April 15, 2014

The Importance of Car-sharing


Addendum: check out this post on Atlantic Cities by Paul Supawanich, which deals with another side of the equation.

Lyft's expansion into Hampton Roads is creating consternation at the State House.  In the past few years, there have been numerous car-sharing innovations, from Zipcar, Lyft, and Uber to websites that allow users to more easily share rides in the same direction.  These services are crucial to the future of urbanism in the US.

But some urbanists have been lukewarm.  Fundamentally, they say, shared cars are still cars.  These critics are missing the bigger picture.  Car-sharing services allow vastly more people to give up car ownership.  One recent study suggested that Zipcar and other car-sharing services replace 32 private cars with one shared car and have resulted in as many as 500,000 fewer new car sales since their appearance.  Each of those private cars was taking up space in the city and resulting in more traffic. 

Shared cars take all expenses of car ownership and boil them down to a trip cost.  This is a critical change.  Car ownership forces high fixed expenditures that become sunk costs for the owners.  They've already shelled out for the car, so they might as well drive it.  The car reorients its owner's brain towards living and shopping in places that were conveniently laid out for cars, rather than for people.

Think of it this way.  Here's all the trips that a hypothetical family living in a relatively walkable urban area might make in 3 months.  We'll say... central Winchester.  The height of the bar represents the marginal value of having a car for each trip and the trips are organized from most to least valuable.



Once the accumulated value of the trips on the left is enough to justify owning a car, suddenly housing and shopping decisions are made based on the car.  Since you're already driving to work every day, you might as well live in a place where you can only get to work via car.  And your company might as well build an office that you can only get to via car.  And your city might as well design its infrastructure around the fact that none of those employees are driving.  And transit options disappear without customers.  And now, suddenly, the marginal value of owning the car is extremely high for every commute, every errand, and even every optional trip.  Indeed, you risk being unemployed and living in social isolation without it.

The secret of the shared car's ability to reduce vehicle trips lies in the marginal (meaning additional) value of the trips that people are currently taking.  Every time you think about going somewhere, you have decisions to make.  Do you drive to work or bike today (this is called "mode choice")?  Do you run up to the grocery to get an extra box of pancake mix or do you wait until 3 when you'll be at the dentist already (this is called "trip-chaining")?

Some of those trips are extremely valuable - eg running your wife to the hospital when she goes into labor or (to use a less extreme example) being able to visit your cousins in a rural area - so much so that they force you to own a car.  While there are lots of costs associated with driving, the biggest ones are fixed (or "capital") costs - the price of the car and its depreciation, the maintenance and upkeep of the vehicle, insurance and taxes, etc.

The costs people weigh when deciding what mode to use are variable costs - often just gasoline.  Even these costs are usually underestimated.  Maintenance from additional mileage doesn't factor in for most people.  And buying gas is such a habit that few people actually sit down before each trip and calculate the cost of the trip.

All that to say, the real financial benefits of not driving only come when one can avoid even owning a car.  And the really economically correct choices are made only when all auto-related costs are boiled down into a trip-by-trip cost that the driver can weigh against the value of the trip.  Car sharing schemes allow people who are already close to being able to live without a car to finally give up car ownership.


Thursday, April 3, 2014

"Elected" Representatives

I've been exploring the 2013 House of Delegates election results a bit lately.  Here's a funny result of the two-party system and our efficiently gerrymandered districts.  In orange are the 59 districts whose representative's did not face either a primary challenger or a serious opponent in the general election.  Of those 59, 42 received 90% or more of the vote in their district.  Not many elected officials in developed countries can boast vote totals like that.  The 5th District's Israel D. O'Quinn takes the cake with no primary and 98.7% of the general election vote, just 1.3% short of the percentage captured by Kim Jong Un in his most recent election.

Thursday, March 27, 2014

Revised Development Projections

http://statchatva.org/2014/03/27/turning-population-projections-into-development-projections/


I've been working on a revised version of the development projection images that I did a while back.  I wrote a long post about it on Stat Chat that has the full images and some commentary on them.  Here I wanted to explain a little more of the technical background on how I made them.



How Is This Constructed?

The model starts with a random value in a Poisson distribution that simulates the likelihood of development.  This distribution captures the fact that some parcels will develop seemingly at random.  As different circumstances change, more and more areas will develop until finally the vast majority of land in an urban area will develop.  After that, some undeveloped plots will remain for a while and a few will simply never develop.

The values in this raster are then raised by adding a score based on the driving time to major employment centers.  This is because most development is and has been automobile-driven.  The shape of an urban area is highly predictable based on the driving time to an employment center.  Lastly, I reduced the likelihood of development based on the slope of the terrain and subtracted all national and state parks, wetlands, military bases, conservation easements, and local parks that were in some way preserved.  I then split this model up into planning district commissions because they roughly encompass metro areas that expand outward from a core.

The density that I used was the same density of development in the district that I was adjusting.  So if the developed areas of a planning district had a density of 1000 persons per acre, that's the density I used for the predicted new residents also.  These densities are likely to be off because of several factors.  They could be too high because, while areas have been gaining population over the last 50 years, the existing population has also been decentralizing and new residents are likely to buy the lowest density homes on the periphery.  On the other hand, they could be too low because, as areas grow in size, they become denser and each new person's marginal amount of developed area is a little smaller.  Additionally, the trend in recent years has swung the other way, as I pointed out earlier in the post.  For lack of a better model, I considered it a wash and stuck with the existing density.

Cities and driving distances:



Slope:



Conserved land:



Growth likelihood raster and planning district boundaries.  Some counties are shared by planning districts - I had to assign these to one district and deduct their population numbers from the other.






I'd be very interested to hear of ways you think this could be improved or additional factors that could be added in.  One I thought of was buffering around the Chesapeake Bay and other bodies of water to account for the attraction of living by the water.  Another is doing a more comprehensive service area just around the roads to get more of the development aligned with roads rather than "speckled" about.  The problem with that is that new developments come with new roads and you don't know where they're going to be.

Wednesday, March 19, 2014

MSA's and Commuting

New post on Statchat looking at the dependence of rural counties on nearby urban areas.

Percent of workers commuting to the Washington, DC area:

Wednesday, March 12, 2014

In Which I Acquire a New Toy


Namely - Tom Gross's cartogram script for ArcGIS

Virginia counties distorted to make area correspond to population:


Where you from?

Why do Hampton Roads and Northern VA seem so different from the rest of Virginia?  At the macro level, it's pretty obvious - the influence of the Federal government in DC and the military in Hampton Roads.  But it's even more obvious on this map, which shows the percentage of the population born in Virginia.  Blue means born here, red means born elsewhere:


Percentages are high in Hampton Roads - especially around military bases.  But almost the entire northern Virginia metro area is in the red.  Fewer than 30% of NoVA residents in most areas were born in Virginia.

Here's another map showing the percentage of the population born outside the U.S.  See the Weldon Cooper Center's post on immigration for more on this subject.


A few quick regressions on excel shows a pretty strong link between places that have more bachelor's degrees, more people born outside VA, and a higher income.  It's not a particularly new revelation - the more education and earning power a person acquires, the more geographically mobile they become.

Tuesday, March 11, 2014

Tract Facts

Nothing too special here in the way of analysis - was just curious about a few subjects so I thought I'd throw them onto a census tract map.  The roads are interstates to help you get your bearings.

Percent of population 25 years and older who have a Bachelor's degree or higher:


 Adults that are currently married:


 Percent of population who moved in the last year:


Monday, March 10, 2014

Sprawl: A Compact History

I am currently reading Robert Bruegmann's well-researched screed against the planning establishment's complaints about sprawl.  It's an excellent read and a tremendous hairshirt for all students steeped in planning school dogma.  In the end, though, his arguments succumb to many of the same historical reductions and internal contradictions that he is decrying in others.  Just a few great quotes that stuck out to me:


"It is possible that even when a small, remote star explodes, this event can reorder the entire gravitational system of a galaxy. A slight wobble in the axis of a planet can mean drastic warming in one area and cooling in another. So it is with urban systems, the main difference being that the most basic element in the urban system is the individual human being who can think and make decisions. Any change made by any member of any neighborhood affects, to some degree, everyone else in the metropolitan area."

p. 94

"The term 'sprawl' has never had a coherent or precise definition.  This has been one of the reasons it has been such a powerful polemical tool.  Thinking of it as a blank screen on which a great many people project their own feelings of discontent with contemporary urban conditions is a good way to approach the history of the anti-sprawl movement.  Because of the lack of a precise agreement about what sprawl is, individuals have been free to rally around certain broad but quite abstract concepts as a way to explain what is wrong with developments they see around them without necessarily agreeing on any specific diagnosis of the problems or any concrete set of prescriptions.  It has allowed people with radically different assumptions to find common cause."

p. 115

"The same homebuyers who might try to maximize their personal advantage in buying a suburban house are the voters who elect government officials and who push for land-use regulations that will benefit them, often at the price of other parts of the population.  Is it logical to think that landowners would suddenly act in a completely different fashion when they engage in political rather than economic transactions?  Nor is the kind of behavior that puts personal interest above community welfare peculiar to low-density settlements.  The resident of a central city who tries to block the badly needed expansion of a hospital next door to his apartment building because it would block his view is acting in a similar fashion."

p. 99

"Affluent residents of Youngstown who move to the exurban fringe are merely exploiting one of the most important assets available in the metropolitan area - a large supply of attractive land at low prices.  Although at first glance it appears that the dispersal to the edges does little other than eviscerate the central cities and displace agriculture, in many cases, the possibility of building a house on a large tract of inexpensive land in the exurban fringe is the one thing that continues to attract middle-class residents who might otherwise flee to more dynamic regions.  If, as is quite likely, Youngstown's downtown and central residential districts revive, it will not be despite sprawl but because sprawl has made it possible for the metropolitan area to retain residents during extremely difficult years."

p. 89

"In the early years of the 21st century, it appears that the forces of renewal and gentrification are becoming dominant in an increasing number of central cities.  The old 'crisis of the central city,' in which jobs were departing and property values plunging, could well turn out to have been a short-lived phenomenon...

Many smart growth activists believe that as people return to the city in greater numbers, this movement of people will create population gains and an increased density that will reduce the pressure for outward expansion.  Increasingly,  however, as affluent citizens have moved to the center, they are doing just what their counterparts have long done in the suburbs.  They have found that they can use zoning ordinances, historic preservation measures, environmental regulations, and other means to resist continued change, to control the appearance and character of their neighborhoods, and to stop densities from rising.  In city after city, the old zoning codes have been downzoned time and again to reduce the ultimate possible population and prevent existing densities from rising."

p.57-58

"What few people seemed to notice was the way the rising fortunes of the center, like their earlier decline, were directly connected to developments at the edge.  As more and more businesses and people, including even some of the least affluent members of the urban community, arrived at the urban periphery, it lost much of its exclusivity and social cachet.  The number of individuals at the very top of the social ladder who wished to buy large houses in the farthest subdivision declined dramatically in the last decades of the twentieth century.  As this happened, the central city and older established suburbs began to regain some of the luster they had lost in the postwar decades.

One of the ironies of this revival is that while central cities have traded on their 'traditional' character, much of what is most attractive about them is the fact that so many of the things that once defined them have disappeared.  The decanting outwards of all kinds of manufacturing and warehousing functions led to dramatic reduction in street congestion, truck traffic, and pollution.  This allowed city centers to become increasingly attractive to those who have the choice to live anywhere they wish in the metropolitan area and  who in previous decades might well have chosen to live in the suburbs or exurbs."

p. 53-54

- Robert Bruegmann

Thursday, March 6, 2014

More Pavement

I continue my quest to be the Ken Pomeroy of impervious surfaces.  Here's a nicer visual with new data from Lynchburg and James City County, giving us a much smoother and more indicative index - from dense city to mixed city to suburban county to suburban/exurban county.


Monday, March 3, 2014

Four reasons bikes should not pay the same fines as cars

Thanks to Brian Davis at Cville Tomorrow for publishing this.  The link is here.  I've edited the manuscript a bit as a result.

Bike tickets are on the rise and they carry the same fines and legal consequences that vehicle infractions do.

This system is a bad one for four big reasons:

1. The cost of a ticket is disproportionate to the cost of riding a bicycle

The cost of a traffic ticket is scaled to the cost of owning and driving an automobile.  One ticket costs about as much as it costs the average American to own and drive a car for a week.  That’s enough to be a reasonable deterrent, but not an unreasonable expense for someone paying an average of almost $8,000 a year to own a car and drive it.

For most riders, bikes are a cheaper alternative.  They are a way for people with less disposable income to get access to some of the same opportunities as those who can afford to drop money on cars, gas, and parking.  They allow people to trade comfort and some speed for savings and exercise.  Getting a bicycle ticket threatens this trade-off immensely.

While $150 is a drop in the bucket for a car owner, it may be half the cost of a bicycle and more than it costs to ride a bike for a year.  That’s a huge risk.  A ticket a year only slightly raises the cost of driving.  A bike ticket a year makes biking almost not worth it, putting another car back on the road or depriving someone of reliable transportation.  Compare it to the outrage drivers felt in 2007 when the state legislature tried to increase fines by 700% to make up our traditional transportation budget shortfall.  The costs were simply unreasonable for drivers to absorb in comparison to the other costs of driving.  Current ticket prices for bikers are just as unreasonable.

2. Bicycles are not 2-ton blocks of metal that go 70 mph and kill thousands of people a year

Fines are high for traffic violations because traffic violations are a big deal.  Cars kill over 30,000 people a year in the United States and injure hundreds of thousands of others.  Cars are weapons that can do serious and expensive damage to others on the road – including cyclists, whom they kill at a rate of over 600 a year.

Bicycles, to put it simply, do not.  The dangers posed by the two modes are several orders of magnitude apart.  As much as drivers may rail about the behavior of bicyclists being unsafe or causing accidents, there are almost no recorded incidents of a vehicle occupant being injured because of the actions of a bicyclist.  You have a better chance of becoming President of the United States than of getting hurt by a bicyclist while you are in a car.  The only people reckless bikers put in danger on the road are themselves.

Bikes can be a danger to pedestrians, especially if ridden on the sidewalk.  Yet they still injure pedestrians much less frequently (and less severely) than cars do.  By comparison, around four thousand pedestrians are killed by cars every year and tens of thousands are injured.

3. It is often difficult for bicyclists to follow the rules safely

We are not yet at the point where cycling according to the rules is an easy feat.  Many traffic signals only change when a car pulls up to them.  Rocks, glass, snow, and other debris in bike lanes often force bicycles to swerve in and out.  When they do so, they risk being charged with “reckless driving,” a widely abused citation for cyclists.  Coming to a complete stop rather than a rolling stop at stop signs forces cyclists to put a foot down and waste additional time starting again, angering motorists behind.  Cyclists can get tickets for failing to signal turns, which is often unsafe.  While signaling, the cyclist risks losing control of the bicycle as well as the ability to brake with that hand.  These and other problems are not insurmountable, but the roadway is still a harsh place for bikes.  The rules are not as tailor-made or easy to follow as they are for vehicles.

4. Motorists are almost never held responsible for collisions with bicycles

Negligent drivers who injure passengers in another car can expect to pay hefty insurance bills and potentially face legal consequences.  But if they hit or even kill a cyclist, there are rarely any consequences at all.  Read Daniel Duane's excellent op-ed in the NYT: "Is it ok to kill cyclists?"   It's a nationwide issue, but Virginia is a particular offender.  We are consistently unable to get even common sense protections for bicyclists on the road, including a shameful vote in committee last month to kill a bill protecting bikes from "dooring."

The Economist has this to say about American traffic laws: "[M]otorists in America generally receive no punishment whatsoever for crashing into or killing cyclists, even when the accident is transparently their fault. This insane lacuna in the justice system reflects extreme systemic prejudice by drivers against cyclists, and would be easy enough to fix."

The only place where cyclists are treated as equals is when being fined for traffic violations.

The solution: better infrastructure, better laws, rescaled fines

Bike lanes and separated cycle tracks are the only way to make cycling truly safe and effective as a means of transportation.  In the meantime, we need two things:

1. Amended rules for cyclists that allow them to use their natural advantages to everyone’s benefit and grant them the same common sense protection given to every other type of vehicle.

2. A scaled-down fee schedule.  Moving violations should cost about one tenth the equivalent vehicle fine to reflect the difference in cost of ownership.  Most bike tickets should range from $10 to $20.  Before this can work, Virginia needs to fix its absurd system of flat “court costs.”

If we scaled down these costs and fixed our bicycle laws, then I might be in favor of handing out more tickets.



Thursday, February 27, 2014

Moving

While I am keeping this blog and will continue to use it for more experimental projects and opinions, I have recently joined UVA's Weldon Cooper Center for Public Service, and will be largely migrating over to its Stat Chat blog.  You may know them as the source of Virginia's population projections and the creator of the Racial Dot Map.  See my first post on the movements of millennials and their spatial gender gap:

What are the young people up to these days?



Wednesday, February 19, 2014

Age and Place

I want to start what may become a series of several posts looking at the movement of people throughout their lifetimes.  I'll leave you with this graphic for now - which shows the relative concentration of each age group by census tract.  Red means the age group is overrepresented, blue means it is underrepresented, yellow means it is proportionally represented.

There is, as you would expect, a drastic shift around age 20 to college towns, followed by a shift to central urban areas, and then a long dispersion out to suburban counties and rural areas.  The cycle for children, unsurprisingly, mirrors the cycle for those age 30 to 50ish.


Wednesday, February 12, 2014

Ten Walmarts (and other stores) that are larger than their downtowns

 1. Downtown Waynesboro and Walmart

I once witnessed a conversation between Waynesboro, VA's Director of Planning Michael Barnes and a citizen.  The citizen asserted that at Walmart, there was always lots of parking right in front of the store, whereas you had to park and walk if you went downtown.  He responded something to the effect of: "I bet if you drew a line from the middle of the Walmart parking lot to the door, walked around the store, checked out, and walked back to the car, you'd have gone farther than if you parked in Constitution Park lot [a parking lot in downtown Waynesboro that is never full] and visited every store on the 300 block of Main Street."

He was absolutely correct.  The sense we have of space while in a vehicle is radically different from the sense of space we have as a pedestrian.  Walkable places have an entirely different scale - a density of connections and destinations that provide a full city experience within a very short physical distance - often a quarter to a half mile (or a five to ten minute walk).  Automobile-oriented places provide the same grid of connections and destinations at a dramatically expanded scale.  The time distance is still the same - everything is accessible in five to ten minutes.  But that means something different in terms of space - more like five miles than a half mile.

There's no particular political agenda behind this post except to illustrate the difference in scale that exists between places that were meant to be experienced on foot and places meant to be experienced by car.  The stores that are superimposed over the main street blocks are at the exact same scale.

2. Staunton (with Walmart and Lowes)



3. Front Royal (Walmart and Lowes)


4. Winchester's pedestrian mall (with both Winchester Walmarts)


5. Harrisonburg's Court Square (with the townie Walmart)

 

6. Warrenton (Walmart and Home Depot)


7. Danville


8. Leesburg (Target, Costco, and Dockers)


9. Norfolk's Granby Street (you can also see Scope and MacArthur Mall), with the Battlefield Walmart, Sam's Club, and Garden Ridge - I almost stuck Kohl's in too because its parking lot is so huge when put together with the others.


10. Culpeper - Davis and Main Streets at the Amtrak station.




Sunday, February 9, 2014

Dollar Density

Here's a quick reprise of the 3D density map from a while back.  Rather than each person taking up the same amount of 3-dimensional space, each dollar of household income takes up the same amount of space.  The color of the census tract indicates the median household income, with red being lower and green being higher.  So red tracts that are tall have lots of dollars, but a low median income (aka a high density of people that those dollars are divided among).

Excellent comment from Jim Bacon at baconsrebellion.com:

"The map vividly portrays the overwhelming economic dominance of the Chesapeake Crescent in Virginia’s economy — and Northern Virginia’s dominance within the crescent."